cover of episode The Great Tariff Battle

The Great Tariff Battle

2025/4/8
logo of podcast Dan Snow's History Hit

Dan Snow's History Hit

AI Deep Dive AI Chapters Transcript
People
D
Dan Snow
D
Duncan Brack
Topics
Dan Snow: 我讨论的是19世纪末的英国,一个强大的经济体,它面临着新的挑战,来自崛起的大国的威胁,以及为社会项目筹集资金的机会。保守党,特别是19世纪末执政的保守党,主要转向关税,尽管这样做导致党内分裂。由于保守党内战,在1906年大选中,英国民众给予保守党历史上最惨痛的失败之一。英国民众全面否决了关税,他们反对更昂贵食物,以及关税代表着国家转向内向,放弃了各国和平相处、低贸易壁垒合作的理想。 Duncan Brack: 18世纪末,大多数人是重商主义者,认为世界贸易总量是固定的,各国应尽可能控制更大比例的贸易份额。亚当·斯密和戴维·李嘉图的理论挑战了重商主义,主张自由市场和比较优势,认为国家应专注于具有比较优势的生产,并通过贸易获益。自由贸易理论认为,消除贸易障碍(如关税)能使各国充分发挥比较优势,从而获益。为了维持国内粮食价格,英国政府在19世纪初通过了《谷物法案》(Corn Laws),对粮食进口征税。19世纪,英国工业家和中产阶级对《谷物法案》施加压力,认为高粮价增加了生产成本,阻碍了出口。反谷物法联盟的努力最终导致了《谷物法案》的废除。自由贸易成为英国的国家认同的一部分,低关税政策促进了经济增长和国际合作。自由贸易成为英国的“民族信仰”,这与其作为世界主要工业强国的身份密切相关。19世纪中叶的自由贸易政策促进了英国的经济繁荣和自由党的成功,但英国不可能永远保持世界主要工业强国的地位。对自由主义者来说,自由贸易不仅仅是经济问题,更是打破封建残余、促进公平竞争和社会进步的工具。自由主义者认为自由贸易有助于促进国际和平与合作。19世纪末,其他国家(如德国、美国)的经济发展对英国构成挑战,这些国家对进口商品征收关税,导致英国产业面临竞争压力。其他国家对进口商品征收关税,导致英国产业面临竞争压力,这促使英国考虑采取类似措施。约瑟夫·张伯伦是推动英国转向保护主义的关键人物。张伯伦提出“帝国特惠制”,即对来自殖民地的进口商品给予优惠关税待遇,以加强英国与殖民地之间的联系。张伯伦推动保护主义的动机是多方面的,包括增加社会改革所需的财政收入、加强帝国实力以及应对来自其他国家的竞争。张伯伦的帝国特惠制提案存在缺陷,例如其未能充分考虑帝国自身的粮食供应问题,以及殖民地是否愿意维持其作为原材料供应国的地位。张伯伦开始将保护主义作为维护就业和产业安全的手段,但关税对依赖进口或出口的任何人都可能造成负面影响。1906年大选,自由党取得压倒性胜利,自由贸易成为其竞选的核心议题。自由贸易不仅仅是经济问题,更是与英国的国家认同和价值观紧密相连。自由贸易优于关税,但政府需要积极应对自由贸易对社区和产业的负面影响。自由贸易会对某些产业造成负面影响,政府需要提供支持,帮助受影响的工人。政府未能有效应对自由贸易的负面影响,加剧了对反全球化运动的支持。一些自由党候选人明确表示,他们支持政府采取积极措施,为受自由贸易影响的人们提供社会保障。

Deep Dive

Chapters
This chapter explores the historical context of the Corn Laws in 19th-century Britain, explaining their nature as tariffs on imported grain and their significant impact on British politics. It details the shift from mercantilism to free market theories, the role of the Anti-Corn Law League, and the eventual repeal of the laws in 1846, leading to the birth of the Liberal Party.
  • Corn Laws as tariffs on imported grain
  • Shift from mercantilism to free market theories
  • Role of the Anti-Corn Law League
  • Repeal of Corn Laws in 1846
  • Birth of the Liberal Party

Shownotes Transcript

Translations:
中文

No matter how you travel, it's good to have a plan. Some people plan every minute. No sleep, bus, museum, another museum. While others only plan to take it day by day. When it comes to your finances, a plan is just as important. You can count on Credit Karma to give you the insights you need to understand your options so you can take charge of your financial path and find your way to money. Explore how you can make financial progress with confidence today. Intuit Credit Karma. Karma you can count on.

Hey, this is Naomi Ickparigan, co-host of the podcast Couples Therapy. I wanted to talk to you about Boost Mobile, the newest 5G network in the country. Boost Mobile's new network delivers customers the speed and service they'd expect from the big three, plus groundbreaking benefits you'd only get from a true challenger in the industry, like letting people try the network risk-free for 30 days and offering a $25 per month unlimited plan that's guaranteed to never go up in price.

So visit your nearest Boost Mobile store or find them online at boostmobile.com. When you're a forward thinker, the only thing you're afraid of is business as usual. Workday is the AI platform that transforms the way you manage your people and money today so you can transform tomorrow. Workday, moving business forever forward. Hi, everybody. Welcome to Dan Snow's History Hit. This is the story of a globally dominant economic power.

It's a story of how after decades of enormous growth, of wealth creation, that nation's hitherto unshakable commitment to free trade began to crack. Other nations were emerging as competitors. They were selling goods cheaper. Industries were suffering. Their workforces laid off. And against that backdrop, that great nation turned to the question of tariffs.

I'm talking obviously about Britain at the end of the 19th century, a great economic power that was now facing new challenges, was facing threats from rising powers, and was looking for opportunities to raise revenue to pay for social programmes.

The Conservative Party, in particular the Conservative Party that was in power at the end of the 19th century, largely turned to tariffs, although in doing so they tore themselves apart. And with the Conservative Party in the state of, frankly, in civil war, in the 1906 general election the British public inflicted one of the greatest defeats in electoral history upon that Conservative Party.

The British public sort of comprehensively rejected tariffs. They rejected the prospect of more expensive food. But beyond that, they also rejected the idea that tariffs represented of turning inwards, of giving up on a dream of a world in which the great nations could get along with each other at peace, collaborating with low barriers to trade, to exchange and cooperation.

This is a podcast all about tariffs, how the British right flirted with them just over a century ago and paid a terrible price, thrown out of power for every generation.

To come and tell me that story in this fateful week when the global economies are reeling from the impact of Trump's tariffs, I've got Duncan Brack. He's an expert analyst and policy advisor focusing on the interaction between trade and environmental issues. He's editor of the Journal of Liberal History and has published a couple of articles on this exact subject, liberals and free trade, at the end of the 19th and early 20th centuries.

This, friends, is a deep history of tariffs, fascinating and important at this time. That is a sentence I never thought I would say out loud. Enjoy.

Duncan, thank you so much for coming on the podcast. It's a pleasure to be here. Thank you for inviting me. If we're talking tariffs, given that we're Brits, we probably need to go back and just get those old corn laws mentioned without wanting to traumatise everyone's memories of 19th century history at school. Just what are the corn laws? Why are they tariffs and why do they matter in British politics?

Yeah, so I want to go back, just to start with, to the end of the 18th century, when by and large, most people were mercantilists. They thought that total volume of trade, world trade, was fixed, and it was in countries' interest to try and control as much of a proportion of that as possible, which they would do by controlling colonies, controlling trade routes, things like that.

But Adam Smith and David Ricardo began to undermine that at the end of the 18th, beginning of the 19th century. So Adam Smith came forward with the theory of free markets, promoting specialization of labor so people could concentrate on what they were really good at, and that would promote economic growth, both domestic and international. And David Ricardo adopted that to the theory of comparative advantage, which

The idea that nations could specialize in production that they were good at. Perhaps there might be agriculture, in which case they should produce food and export it. And perhaps other countries like Britain might be good at manufacturers, so they should concentrate on manufactured goods and export those, but import other things that they were less able to produce, like food or less able to produce cost-effectively.

So basically, the idea was that the countries would benefit from trading with each other to realize the benefits of their comparative advantage. So that meant that you wanted to get rid of impediments to trade. You wanted to get rid of tariffs, import duties, export duties, and have open trade as much as possible. And of course, at this stage, Britain was the biggest manufacturing power in the world. So open markets would benefit it most, of course.

So that was the theory. It wasn't accepted for several decades. So then we come on to the debate over the corn laws. Now, in this context, corn means all cereal grains, wheat, oats, barley, rye, etc. Basically, the raw materials for bread.

In Napoleonic Wars, the beginning of the 19th century, pretty much the last time Britain was self-sufficient in food, the price of bread and the price of all the grains rose during the wars and then began to fall as the wars came to an end in 1815. So the government at the time put in place the Corn Laws, or to be accurate, the Importation Act of 1815. And this was passed to maintain high corn prices from domestic production, from production in the UK, by taxing imports.

And that led to high bread prices and there were some food riots and problems like that. But you had the Tory government in power, which wasn't too worried about that.

As the economy began to take off again after the war, there was pressure to relax these. But what they found was that their landowners, particularly Tory landowners, liked the high prices. It meant they got better returns on their investment in agriculture from their estates. So that then led in time over the decades to pressure from the middle classes, and particularly the industrialists, the growing manufacturing base, particularly things like the cotton industry based in Manchester.

The pressure there was to relax those because they saw problems with the costs of importing their raw materials, raw cotton from the States perhaps, and also barriers to exporting their manufactured goods there, the cotton clothes. And also, because food prices were quite high, they had to pay their workers higher wages than otherwise to make sure they could buy the food.

So we saw the growing pressure to relax the Corn Laws, particularly focused around the Anti-Corn Law League, which was founded in 1839. One of the most effective pressure groups, probably before the modern age, used lectures, public meetings, pamphlets, electoral pressure, all of those kind of things. And in the end, it led to Robert Peel as Prime Minister deciding to abolish the Corn Laws in 1846.

He split his own party. He was a Tory prime minister. The Tories split over it, kind of similar to their splits over Europe, but more fundamental. Perhaps a third of the Conservative Party followed him out of the Tory party. The remainder of it remained controlled by the protectionists or landowners who wanted to maintain the Cornwalls. And you saw a parliamentary group formed called the Peelites.

who gradually then gravitated towards the Liberal Party. And the combination of the three parliamentary factions, Radicals, Whigs and Peelites, in 1859 is usually held to mark the birth of a Liberal Party.

And in its DNA, at birth, the Liberal Party was sold on this idea of lowering tariffs so that food could be cheap, even though it was grown abroad, that was okay. It was good for the working man and woman. And it also meant for the industrialists who are part of that coalition, that's great, because then by lowering tariffs, then you encourage other nations to lower their tariffs. Does it make it easier to export your, well, bring in raw materials and then push out manufactured finished products? Yeah.

Yes, that's absolutely right. And what we saw was successive budgets by particularly William Gladstone, who was actually originally a Tory, then followed Peel out of the Conservative Party into the Liberal Party as part of the Peelites, and of course became the great Liberal Prime Minister of the second half of the 19th century. In his budget of 1860, he reduced the number of articles in the British tariff, the number of products on which tariffs were charged, import duties were charged.

There were over 1,000 in 1852. He reduced it to 40 after 1860. So a tremendous expansion of free trade. And the network of free trade treaties grew, particularly in Europe, following the Comte de Chevalier Treaty of 1860. In a sense, this is the beginning of what we saw, a kind of European free trade area that sort of prefigured the European economic community, the common market of like 100 years later.

And this became so embedded in the kind of national image, self-image of Britain, free trade basically became a national obsession. The Times commented in 1859, "Like parliamentary representation or ministerial responsibility, not so much a prevalent opinion as an article of national faith."

And underpinned by the fact that Britain was the most effective industrial power in the world. So it's what's not to like about free trade. It benefits you. It means imports are cheaper and you can export everywhere in the world. But

But then what happens at the end of the 19th century? Does this trading superpower get a little bit nervous? Yeah. So, I mean, this underpinned really the kind of long mid-Victorian economic boom and also the success of the Liberal Party because they were able to attract the industrialists and the middle classes who were steadily enfranchised through successive parliamentary reforms, electoral reforms.

But actually, just before we got on to when they started to break down, it's important to understand this was always much more than just an economic argument. It wasn't about prices and wages, though that was important.

But for the liberals, it was part of the process of tearing down the remnants of the feudal order. It was putting an end to the special treatment enjoyed by the landowners or any kind of vested interest. The idea was that commercial success should be the outcome of hard work and natural talent alone, not the protection of vested interests. So it was kind of the economic twin of democracy. Right.

Right, and it's interesting that interesting, because presumably in the past, it had been all about lobbying. If you grabbed a Stuart King or a Plantagenet, you said, listen, I've got a nice little factory over here, which we're getting some trouble from the men of Antwerp. Can you slap a tariff on them? Presumably it's a system that is prone to that sort of insiderism, corruption and nepotism.

That's absolutely right. In fact, that was one of the arguments deployed later. I mean, Churchill used it actually as a liberal MP. He didn't want to see government become the area where vested interests campaigned or bought influence for their own interests, which you would see with a system of tariffs, which could apply differently to different industries.

And also for the Liberals, as well as that, it was also important on the international scene. Free trade was seen as something as a kind of agency for peace, building links between nations rather than fostering conflict. So the Liberal leader of the Anti-Coronial League and later Liberal MP and Minister John Bright put it, for the disbanding of great armies and the promotion of peace, I rely on the abolition of tariffs on the brotherhood of the nations resulting from free trade in the products of industry.

So it's kind of important to understand free trade. Almost, I think the nearest I can think of sort of comparison today is more like it was what it meant to be British, maybe like the NHS or the BBC or something like that. It was part of the national image, part of the national consciousness. Until, as you say, that began to come under assault towards the end of the 19th century.

And we should say that period of free trade, the middle of the 19th century, lots of colonial wars going on, don't get me wrong, but limited great power wars, given what had come in the 18th century, there were endless, endless giant struggles between the great powers. So it looked as though perhaps free trade, huge advance in prosperity, great scientific and industrial breakthroughs. It looked like this was all one happy package that was leading humanity to the sunlit uplands.

Yes, it was, until the kind of end of the mid-Victorian economic boom. Yes. So what happens? Why do the Victorians lose their faith in free trade? So obviously Britain couldn't remain the main manufacturing nation in the world forever. Other countries were developing their economies, Germany, France, Russia, the United States of America, particularly the USA, with kind of seemingly endless access to natural resources and land, and a steady inflow of cheap labour in terms of immigrants from Europe.

And what was happening was that all these countries were applying tariffs themselves. They were applying import duties against imports from other countries like Britain. So the kind of pressure began for the UK to follow suit, particularly as you could see British industries steadily undercut by cheaper products coming in from the outside. But they were their own industries, American industries or German industries, were protected from competition with British goods by their own import duties levied by their own governments.

And this appealed in particular to Joseph Chamberlain,

who was kind of an interesting character, one of the main political characters of the 19th, end of the 19th century and early 20th century. Originally a radical liberal, kind of pioneer of what was known as municipal socialism, so social reform led by local government. He was mayor of Birmingham from 1873 to 76. He purchased gas and water companies on behalf of the town corporation, cleared slums, introduced city parks, established the medical officer of health and so on.

Godalek to the Parliament was a radical liberal trying to push Gladstone's government into being more ambitious and social reform.

But then Gladstone's other obsession was with home rule for Ireland. And one of the big debates of the 1870s, 1880s was over whether Ireland should be given more self-government. Chamberlain was completely against that. He was an imperialist. He wanted Ireland to remain very firmly with the rest of Britain as the heart of the empire. So he broke with the Liberal Party over the Home Rule Bill in 1886.

and led about 100 MPs, I think, to defeat Gladstone's attempt to introduce Home Run for Ireland. That group then separated from the Liberal Party, became known as the Liberal Unionists, and joined with the Conservatives. So he was in coalition with the Conservatives in the 1880s and '90s and the beginning of the 20th century. And he chose to become Secretary of State for the Colonies from 1895 to 1903.

Because he's kind of developed, he kind of moved on slightly from social reform. His obsession was the way to get Britain safe and powerful in the world. Britain as an island nation was too small to be able to compete by itself with the great empires, Russia, Germany, United States. But with the empire, with the colonies, Australia, Canada, New Zealand, India, the empire could be stronger internationally.

and could compete with them. So he became kind of obsessed with the idea of imperial unity. Yes, and there are many thinkers and historians and philosophers at the time saying the same thing, is that Britain's future lies in, just as the USA and Russia, turning these imperial entities into sort of modern nation-states. Just a slightly odd-looking one with lots of ocean in between its various bits of it. Yes. Yeah, that's right. So

He launched his campaign for imperial preference in 1903. And the background to this was he was frustrated as he still had kind of aims of social reform, but he was in coalition with the conservatives, particularly with the conservatives under Lord Salisbury, prime minister in 1902, who was basically a total reactionary, tried to avoid any kind of social legislation, any kind of progressive reform, also kept Britain free of entangling alliances.

But he stepped down in 1902, so Chamberlain saw his opportunity with the new Prime Minister, Arthur Balfour. So his idea was imperial preference: you would put protection against the rest of the world, against imports from the rest of the world. So you'd apply import duties, tariffs as we usually call them, but you would give a lower rate of duty, or perhaps no import duty at all, to imports coming in from the colonies. So you would tie the British colonies more closely to the UK. So that's known as imperial preference.

You're listening to Dan Snow's History. We're talking about tariffs. More coming up? Maybe. This episode of Dan Snow's History here is brought to you by Policy Genius. Now, if there's one thing I've learned from history, folks...

is that you never quite know what's around the corner. Expecting the unexpected is crucial, and that's where PolicyGenius comes in. They make finding and buying life insurance simple, giving your family a financial safety net to cover everything from mortgage payments to everyday expenses. With PolicyGenius, you can find life insurance policies that start at just $292 per year for $1 million of coverage. Some options are 100% online and let you avoid unnecessary medical exams.

Policy Genius lets you compare quotes from America's top insurers side by side for free with no hidden fees. Their licensed support team advocates for you, answering questions and handling all the paperwork so you don't have to. No matter what stage of life you're at, planning for the future by protecting yourself and your loved ones is a no-brainer. So secure your families tomorrow so you can have peace of mind today. Head to policygenius.com.

to get your free life insurance quotes and see how much you could save.

G'day, America. It's Tony and Ryan from the Tony and Ryan podcast from Down Under. Today we want to talk to you about Boost Mobile, the newest 5G network in the country. These guys are no longer the prepaid wireless company you might remember. They've invested billions into building their own 5G towers across America, transforming the carrier into America's fourth major network alongside the other big dogs. Hoo, hoo!

Yep, they're challenging the competitors by working harder and smarter like this amazing new network they've literally built. The Boost Mobile network together with their roaming partners covers 99% of the US population but 5G speeds not available in all areas. Yep, they have a blazing fast internet and plans for all the latest devices. Visit your nearest Boost Mobile store or find them online at boostmobile.com.

Now at Verizon, we have some big news for your peace of mind. For all our customers, existing and new, we're locking in low prices for three years guaranteed on MyPlan and MyHome. That's future you peace of mind. And everyone can save on a brand new phone on MyPlan when you trade in any phone from one of our top brands. That's new phone peace of mind. Because at Verizon, whether you're already a customer or you're just joining us,

We got you. Visit Verizon today. Price guarantee applies to then current base monthly rate. Additional terms and conditions apply for all offers. If you need inspiration to prepare food, go to Fry's, where you'll find delicious food and delicious ingredients. Choose what you like, and with our low prices, you'll save money. Also, use more than $600 in digital coupons every week, and up to $1 discount per gallon of fuel with your points.

En Fries, encuentra ricos sabores y grandes ahorros. Fries, fresh for everyone. Aplican restricciones en combustible. What's driving this? Is this his politics, his dream of forging a British imperial state? Or is it about, I'm getting very annoyed that we're falling behind in this industrial competition of the world. Other nations are overtaking us. Their economies are growing. They're selling stuff cheaper than we can. Our factories are turning derelict. What's uppermost in his mind?

Yeah, I think it was both of those things. And also, he still wanted to pursue his aims of social reform. He was arguing for old-age pensions, for example, in the Liberal Party in the 1880s and 90s.

But the conservatives would never do that. He needed to raise revenue for pensions and other social reforms. So he saw tariffs as a way of doing that. He also, as I said, wanted to create a strong empire. He thought Britain and the colonies together would be able to compete against the rising empires in Europe and America and Russia. And Britain by itself could not do that. It needed

to be more closely lit to the empire. Ideally, he wanted a kind of imperial federation, whether it be an imperial parliament, a city in London with representatives from all the colonies. The colonies didn't want that themselves. That was too great a loss of political autonomy. And of course, in the days before air travel, that would be quite difficult to sort of handle anyway.

Then he moved on to perhaps, well, fiscal combination, a customs union like the German states had, like the EU does now. But again, that was too much a loss of fiscal autonomy for the colonies to bear. But they were interested in discussing preferential rates of import duty. Indeed, the colonial conference in 1902, the colonies actually came out in favor of that.

Chamberlain's problem was, at the time the UK was recovering from the costs of the Boer War, which finished in 1902, so the government fiscal policy was under strain, they weren't raising enough money. So, in fact, corn duty was brought back again in 1902 purely as a revenue-raising matter to help meet the costs of the war.

So, Chamberlain saw that as an opportunity, rather than get rid of it when the fiscal situation recovered, he argued to keep it in place, but have preferential rates for the colonies. The problem he had there, well, two problems. The Chancellor didn't agree. Charles Ritchie, Conservative Chancellor, was a committed free trader, so he disagreed with the Cabinet's agreement in principle to do this at the end of 1902.

And indeed, by the beginning of 1903, the fiscal position was much stronger. So he wanted to reduce income tax, but at the time, income tax was paid only by the quite rich. So it wasn't nearly as broadly applied as it is today. So he also wanted to do something for the bulk of the population, and the best thing to do was abolish corn duty.

And indeed, he then threatened to resign if he was prevented from doing that. So going completely against what Chamberlain wanted. That's worth pointing out, that point. People have been hearing about this the last few days because income tax is a progressive taxation. It's paid by those with the broader shoulders.

The corn duty is paid by anyone who buys food, buys bread. So it hits poorest member society relatively harder because rich people can afford a few pennies on a sandwich, on a loaf of bread, but the poor can't. Yes, that's right. At the time, income tax had much lower...

proportion of total tax revenue than it does now. And most of government revenue is from indirect taxes, so excise taxes on things like alcohol and food and customs duties. So Chamberlain was then frustrated. The government didn't go for that. Balfour, the Prime Minister, could possibly have

call Ritchie's bluff because actually Chamberlain was a much more important figure in the government than Ritchie. He was very popular in the country. He had a very high profile. He had a lot of following. He was the leader of the Liberal Unionist Party, which is in coalition with the Conservatives. But Balfour was always trying to kind of avoid taking a firm position and just wanted to try and hold his party and his coalition together.

He was always worried about the precedent that Robert Peel had set in the 1840s when he abolished the Corn Laws, but split his party. Balfour didn't want to do that. So he was trying to find a middle way through. So in May 1903, Chamberlain called for an inquiry into the fiscal system, which kind of sounds not too dangerous, but actually he meant basically laying the groundwork for introducing import duties. He wanted to see an empire that was self-sustaining and self-sufficient.

There were quite a lot of problems with his proposal. For a start, only about a quarter of UK imports of food at the time actually came from the colonies. So he didn't explain how the empire was supposed to feed itself if it wasn't importing food from anywhere else. He also kind of assumed that the colonies would be happy to remain static as providers of raw materials to British manufacturers.

The whole aim of imperial preference was to support the British industries. And it wasn't clear the colonies really wanted to do that. And the society wanted to raise money for social reforms, for the course tariffs. And this is what Trump is going to find. Tariffs reduce the volume of trade. So you're going to get less revenue. So you can't both keep out imports and raise money.

So that kind of forced him really into arguing for protection just for its own sake. And here I think he had a kind of point that the kind of critics of globalization do make today, that is kind of fair point, that it may be if you expose your industries to competition, it means some industries are going to go under because they're going to be undercut by other countries' industries who are more efficient to producing whatever it is you're interested in.

Now, that might be better for the country as a whole. It means that you can release resources to go to more profitable activities. So like Britain has moved steadily out of manufacturing into services, which we are quite good at. On the other hand, it's not so good for people who are working in those industries that then go under. It's destabilizing to workers, and it's not much help to say they can buy cheap food if they're out of a job.

So Chamberlain increasingly started to argue about protection as a way of maintaining employment or security of employment, protecting industry against the foreigner. The trouble of course is that actually tariffs are anyone, reliant on imports or exports. So unless you have a completely self-sustaining, self-sufficient economy, tariffs are going to be quite bad. So Balfour was kind of sympathetic actually to Chamberlain's argument, but as I said, desperate to avoid the legacy appeal, desperate to see his party splitting.

And around about a tenth, perhaps 40 or 50 MPs in the unionist coalition at the time were actually fairly convinced free traders. And Balfour was also aware of the electoral dangers of putting tax on food, which is pretty self-evident. Making your bread more expensive is not going to be an attractive electoral slogan.

So he tried to find the middle way, and basically he failed. So he talked a bit about retaliation. So this is what Trump's kind of main line is, saying we will put tariffs on countries who are applying tariffs against us. It was never very clearly meant to sort of general tariff against everyone with negotiated reductions against particular countries, like Trump sort of sometimes hints at, or just specific tariffs against particular countries.

But he also talked about imperial preference. And of course, if you're going to give preference to colonies, it means you have to have tariffs against everybody else. Otherwise, there is no advantage to the colonies. There is no imperial preference. So when you start sort of going down this argument, you end up pretty much always having to argue for a full general tariff, applying probably to all products, including food.

Balfour tried to avoid making this decision and sort of keep his party together, caricatured by a great verse written by the Liberal MP Sir Wilfrid Norson, which began, I'm not for free trade and I'm not for protection. I approve of them both and to both have objections. In going through life, I continually find it's a terrible business to make up one's mind.

So what he did was basically force the free trading ministers in his cabinet out at the end of 1903. He thought it was impossible to maintain compromise when he had three free trade ministers, including Ritchie, the chancellor, determined to stick to free trade. They resigned, effectively forced out in September of 1903.

And then he didn't mind that, but it was followed by the Duke of Devonshire in October. Now, Duke of Devonshire was a major political figure. He was the original liberal unionist leader alongside Chamberlain back in the 1880s. And he stayed true to his liberal free trade inheritance that obviously he split with Gladstone over Ireland. And that was a major loss, kind of helped to undermine the government. And then Chamberlain resigned in turn because he had no commitment to food taxes.

So that meant that Chamberlain was unleashed. So Balfour was kind of relieved at these resignations to start with. The trouble is Chamberlain was then unleashed to begin campaigning within the party. And one thing that Chamberlain always been very good at was political organization. So he formed the Tariff Reform League, which by 1905 had 250 branches. In June of 1903, his unionist opponents set up the Unionist Free Food League, which

But they were sort of more like a campaign with generals and no leaders. They were just a number of MPs, no real support in the unionist parties. And basically Chamberlain steadily took over both the Conservative Party and the Liberal Unionist Party, encouraging them to adopt his views. And that meant that increasingly free trade supporting unionist MPs were deselected and

And no less than 12 of them crossed the floor in 1904 and 1905 to join the Liberal Party, including, of course, Winston Churchill, who became a major asset to the Liberal Party.

And legislation just ground to a halt completely as the unionists repeatedly split over fiscal debates in Parliament. And basically the last two years of Balfour's government machine, very little indeed. And they then got utterly smashed in the 1906 general election, one of the great progressive landslides in British history up there with 1945, 1997 and 2024.

That's absolutely right. So the 1996 election was the greatest liberal landslide ever. 400 MPs elected, conservatives down to just over 150. They lost two thirds of their seats. It was the biggest election defeat for the conservatives until last year. And free trade was, it wasn't the only issue in the campaign, but it was the major one, core of the liberal campaign. And they focused, of course, as you would expect on the consumer interest in cheap food.

So I'll just quote from one liberal leaflet, which is actually directed mainly at women. Of course, women didn't have the vote then, but they had influence on their husbands and sons. So the leaflet said, you know how difficult it is to provide for your families. If Mr. Chamberlain succeeds, you will find it more difficult to pay for the food for your families and the clothes that they wear. If you want to stave off hard times, in capital letters, have nothing to do with Mr. Chamberlain or protection, but urge your husbands and sons to vote for liberals and free traders.

Or another leaflet, half a million copies of another leaflet put it, if you want your loaf, you must shut up, Joe. And coming back to what I was talking about before, it wasn't just about cheap food. The Liberal campaign portrayed tariff reform as an attempt to turn the clock back to a narrow, harmful, protective system, which might help a few specialist companies, a few sort of best interests, but would hit consumers and damage the economy as a whole. It was kind of against the broad interest of most of the people.

So unionist free traders were, as I said, basically driven out of the party. There were only about 15 or 20 candidates allowed to stand in 1906, the 1996 election, and most of them were opposed by unionist tariff reformers. Party discipline was a bit looser in those days. You had actually unionists fighting unionists.

One of the problems, of course, that most of them, they weren't stupid. They could see the electoral dangers of taxing food. So a lot of Unionist general election manifestos, there wasn't so much a central manifesto then, but the candidates all published their own election statements. And most of them were convinced tariff reformers, but

But about half of the candidates' election addresses, when they're analysed, were notably evasive on the extent of the tariffs they advocated, and very few explicitly argued for a general tariff and taxes on food. And you can kind of see why. The Tariff Reform League issued lots of leaflets and booklets issued during the campaign. They were full of statistics attempting to prove that prices overall would not rise, but they also promised tax reductions to offset increase in prices of food. They were trying to have it both ways, and it really didn't work.

And there is a great quote from the Manchester Guardian when the results were known. And they were talking particularly about the election results in Lancashire. Wow.

Gosh, okay. So on the back of tariffs, the Liberals enter government and make many sweeping changes that change the character of British politics and government and life. That's right. As I said before, this wasn't just an argument about taxes and cheap food and stuff like that. That was important, but it was a threat to what was seen as the British character. Britain stood for free trade and fair competition everywhere.

and an open society and wasn't in favour of vested interests. So that was why free trade was such a hold on the national imagination. I think it wasn't just an economic argument that we would see it in today. So that's quite different from what it was then. There was enormous support for free trade. I said there were campaigns, there were leaflets, there were

booklets, there were mass meetings. The Free Trade Union organised thousands of meetings under run-up to the 1906 campaign. The nearest I can think of in my lifetime is probably the campaign over Brexit, the way in which it mobilised so much passion on both sides. But in this case, obviously, the progressive side won in their free trade. As we now look across the world at potentially entering a new era of tariffs, what do you think the lessons from this particular period are? So I think...

I mean, free trade is better than tariffs. It's always going to be better. If you put barriers in the way to trade in products and services, you're going to make them more expensive. The basis of Ricardian comparative advantage is right. Some countries are better able to produce some products or services than others. And the maximum increase in general welfare is gained by allowing them to trade freely with each other.

But you have to be aware of the downsides. And I think this is where free traders were a bit weak and the kind of trade liberalization supporters now need to pay more attention to the impacts of free trade, or as we would call it now, globalization on communities and industries. Because it does mean that some companies, some sectors, some industries will suffer

and be replaced by others. So I think to be able to support free trade, you have to have governments that are very active in providing support to employers who have lost their jobs because they work in uncompetitive industries. They need to be very interventionist about providing training and education and support while they look for other jobs. And certainly the British, successive British governments have not always been very good at that. Some European governments, I think, have handled it better.

But it often seemed, I think, in the sort of 80s and 90s, the kind of heyday of neoliberalism and opening of markets, that trade liberalization was being pursued for its own sake. And you always have to remember, I think, what the outcome of it is. And there are negative outcomes as well, and you have to be prepared to adjust to that.

And I think the argument against globalization has got stronger and has fueled support for people like the Reform Party or various right-wing parties in Europe because actually government's not been very good at coping with the negative impacts of trade and liberalization.

Of course, this wasn't such an issue right back at the beginning of the 19th century because government simply didn't have the capacity to do that kind of thing. Though, of course, the Liberal government elected in 1906 did institute, basically laid the foundations of the welfare state, brought in a whole raft of social reforms, which would have been the beginning of that necessary supportive framework.

Yes. Was that supported framework linked to that? Did they make that link themselves? Look, we are hugely committed to free trade. We understand that the world has changed and the Germans are better than us at making these funny new things called automobiles. And as a result, we are going to use the wealth that we generate in this global environment, this free trade environment, but we're going to use it to try and ameliorate some of the worst effects of it. I mean, was that link made at the time?

Yes, some Liberal candidates did make the case explicitly that they were not content to remain simply passive free traders.

You needed to see government taking a position of providing a kind of safety net for people and to raise standards of living and housing, to invest in education, to provide pensions, labor exchanges, all the kind of things like that. I don't think it was so strongly linked to trade because that was just the kind of the state of the country at the end of the 19th century, beginning of the 20th century. Industrialization had led to increasing wealth.

in aggregate and for quite a lot of people, but there were also many people who lived in poverty or were held back by illness or disability and so on. So it wasn't so explicitly linked to free trade, I think. It was just the kind of general state of the country. Things like the fact that some of that 50% of volunteers for the Boer War had to be rejected because they were unfit for military service really drove home to people just what the problems were with an industrial economy which wasn't providing for its poorer section.

And so some liberal candidates made the link explicitly with free trade. But in general, I think it wasn't. It was a broader issue than that. Duncan, thank you so much for coming and talking all about this. It's so funny because I remember reading all this. When you read 39 Steps as a kid and so much of that literature, Edwardian literature, there's free trade and tariffs is all in there. And as a kid in the 90s, the noughties, you're thinking, what is all this stuff? But here we are. That's how history works. It's back again. So thank you for coming on the podcast. It's a pleasure. It's good to talk to you.

Strap in. You're in the race with F1 TV Premium. See what the race director sees with custom multi-view. Watch every jaw-dropping moment in live 4K UHD across up to six screens uninterrupted. Experience ultimate live immersion with F1 TV Premium. Available on selected devices.

Fries.

Fresh for everyone. Aplican restricciones en combustible.