We're sunsetting PodQuest on 2025-07-28. Thank you for your support!
Export Podcast Subscriptions
cover of episode Post-Bidenomics and what comes next

Post-Bidenomics and what comes next

2025/2/14
logo of podcast The New Bazaar

The New Bazaar

AI Deep Dive AI Chapters Transcript
People
J
Jared Bernstein
Topics
Jared Bernstein: 我认为左翼和右翼经济学家之间存在可以达成共识的可能性,机会区就是一个很好的例子,它通过税收激励引导投资流向低收入社区。虽然机会区项目也存在一些批评的声音,但我认为只要设置好防护措施,它就能发挥积极作用。此外,在一些基本经济原则上,例如机会成本和财政可持续性,左翼和右翼经济学家之间也存在一些共同点。当然,在最低工资、工会和社会保障等问题上,仍然存在一些分歧。 在拜登政府时期,我们取得了一些成就,例如在几乎整个任期内都保持了充分就业的劳动力市场。然而,我们也犯了一些错误,例如在信息传递方面做得不够好,没有充分考虑到那些正在努力应对高物价的人们的感受。此外,美国救援计划可能加剧了通货膨胀,虽然当时我们有充分的理由采取强有力的措施应对疫情的影响,但事后看来,这项计划的规模可能过大。 在贸易政策方面,我认为我们应该与盟友进行尽可能多的全球化合作,同时也要认识到全球化的益处和成本。在拜登政府时期,贸易流动保持强劲,外国直接投资尤其强劲。但是,我们也采取了一些被认为过于保护主义的措施。 关于工会,我认为我们应该关注的是工人获得公平待遇的议价能力,而不是工会密度百分比。工会可以帮助工人获得公平的待遇,特别是在存在单边买方市场的情况下。但是,工会也可能采取一些不利于经济发展的行动。 在住房问题上,我认为联邦政府可以通过向地方政府提供资金并附加条件来解决住房问题,例如减少排他性分区。此外,联邦政府还可以通过补贴来帮助建设经济适用房。 关于人工智能,我认为人工智能更有可能成为劳动力的补充,而不是替代品。但是,我们也需要关注人工智能可能对劳动力市场造成的负面影响。 总的来说,我认为我们应该更加关注政府失灵,并努力在市场失灵和政府失灵之间取得平衡。 Cardiff Garcia: 在与Jared Bernstein的对话中,我探讨了拜登经济政策后的经济走向,以及一些相关的政策议题。我们讨论了在两党之间寻找共识的可能性,以及在机会区项目等具体政策上的合作。我们还探讨了贸易政策、全球化、通货膨胀、工会、住房危机、人工智能以及财政政策等问题。在这些问题上,我们既探讨了取得的成就,也反思了需要改进的地方,例如信息传递和政策制定过程中的不足。

Deep Dive

Shownotes Transcript

Translations:
中文

Hi, I'm Cardiff Garcia, and this is The New Bazaar. Coming up on today's show. The extent to which people of different persuasions are starting to talk to each other represents a kind of urgency that if we don't figure this out, we're all screwed. And I like that. Jared Bernstein on this very strange, confusing, tumultuous economic hour that we find ourselves in.

Jared Bernstein is our guest today. For a long time, he's been devoted to public service and economic policymaking, going all the way back at least to the 90s when he was deputy chief economist at the Department of Labor. He's had various roles in the Obama and Biden White Houses. Most recently, he was chair of President Biden's Council of Economic Advisors. And he's been out of that role for only a few weeks. He's been writing a newsletter. He has joined

The Substackosphere? The Substackiverse? Is that what we call it now? That sounds good, yeah. I think I have. As a boomer, some of those movements get a little tricky for me, but yeah. Me too, and I'm not yet a boomer, sad to say. But what I'm really hoping, Jared, is that you're feeling unconstrained, unleashed, and

maybe even a little loose in the lips in the way that people can't be when they still work in the government. So first of all, welcome to the new bazaar. Is that the case? Are you ready to unburden yourself with some, I don't know, honest but maybe impolite thoughts about politics and the economy? Definitely I am. I feel like I should lie down on a couch and let it rip. But yes, to the extent that I'm comfortable, I definitely don't have the comms team looking over my shoulder the way it was back then.

complicated question. How does it feel to be out of the government now and watching what's happening? Yeah. How are you doing? Yeah. Well, it's interesting because I think personally I'm doing well. I have time to exercise every day and I'm going to a lot of MD appointments that I wasn't able to do when I was in the White House. But yes, watching what's happening is, of course, of great concern. It feels like

The Constitution is kind of being shredded in front of our eyes, and the rule of law is being morphed into the law of rule in ways which I'm finding unsettling. I worry about a lot of the economic policy that's coming down the pike. And then, you know, at the same time, I want to be careful not to sort of overreact. We have a $29 trillion economy. We left them a great economy, and it takes a lot to knock it off its pace, but a lot of competing vibes in that regard. I'm going to say you're doing okay.

Yeah, I think that's a good assessment. Like it sounds like your head is still in the moment, right? In the political moment. I exercise every day now practically. And that's a big positive change. That's a big change from when you were in the White House. Just you didn't have the time, yeah. How many hours did you work each day when you were in the White House?

Well, they always say in the White House, someone says the meeting's at 7 and you say a.m. or p.m. And so I worked from probably, you know, 7 a.m. to 8 p.m., not always in the office. And sometimes later than that. A lot of times we would have a data report that would come out the next day. So you'd get the CPI on Wednesday. We'd get it Tuesday night. We'd have to write a memo for the president. And that could take us into the late hours trying to figure out what we wanted to say and how to compress that information into coherent memo for him.

And you were the chair. So if everybody working there is taking their cues from you and you were working 13 hour days, imagine what they're going through too. Well, now I'm getting worried that some of our junior economists are listening to this and they're thinking like, dude, I was working until 11 while you were back home. Going off to a nice little dinner. Exactly. Yeah. So there were those who worked harder than me. Let's be clear about that.

Fair enough. Let's talk a little bit about your story before we talk about economics, okay? You are something of, I think, an oddity, right? You've got a lot of credibility with the left, obviously, because of your past concern for the worker. And in some cases, for example, like your skepticism of big trade deals, things like that.

But you do have a lot of admirers on the right, even if what they admire might be your character instead of like necessarily your views. But you have worked across party lines before, including, I should note in full disclosure here, you were one of the co-founders of...

of the Economic Advisory Board at the Economic Innovation Group, which produces this show. The other co-founder was Kevin Hassett, who's now the director of the National Economic Council for President Trump. So you've done that before. I'm kind of curious to know if you have lost faith in the possibility that that sort of thing can still happen.

No, I haven't. Kevin is a friend and he's now one of the top economists in the Trump administration. I think he's probably pushing back against some of the bad ideas, but maybe losing some arguments. So I have actually a fair bit of faith in his economics, except when it comes to taxes, where we just...

We'll never see eye to eye. Well, you know, to me, his views on trickle down or supply side tax cuts is like religion, impervious to evidence. But I know he sees that differently. But on a lot of other things, including, by the way, as I'm sure you know from your EIG work, what became Opportunity Zones comes out of a white paper that Kevin and I wrote. So I definitely believe. We should stop, by the way, to tell everybody Opportunity Zones is an idea that was passed actually as part of the 2017 Tax Cut and Jobs Act.

essentially is a tax incentive to get investors to invest in some low-income neighborhoods throughout the country. And

Correct. It's looking pretty good right now, all right? You know, it has its critics, and I've been one of them in terms of if you don't put up guardrails, it can easily become a loophole. But with the proper guardrails, I think it can funnel capital into places that need it. And so that, yes, I totally think there are ideas that left and right economists can agree on, and I don't think that's the null set at all.

But I guess one of the things I've tried to do is to listen to everybody who's arguing in earnest, regardless of their political sensibilities. What are the sort of philosophical points of overlap, do you think, between your set of views and the sets of views of people that you maybe largely disagree with, but you do have those points of overlap?

I think there's some basic overlap on fundamental economic principles, concepts of sort of opportunity costs. If you're doing something here, then it's harder to do it there. The idea of fiscal sustainability is something I share with some folks on the other side, although sometimes I worry that for them it's more rhetoric than actual policy intention. I think, you know, running a very strong macro economy should be a pretty bipartisan thing.

I think, and I think the opportunity zone is a good example of this. I think that capital markets have value and should be tended to and can, I don't view kind of profitability as necessarily a bad thing, you know, by a long shot. So I think there's some overlap there. Okay.

Do you agree with the notion that's become quite widespread that we don't even really exist in a kind of left versus right environment anymore, that now the lines are drawn between what you might call

anti-institutionalist people who want to sort of just fundamentally change the way we do everything versus people who, yeah, they think that institutions need reform, but the institutions themselves also have a lot of positives going for them. And I'm kind of curious to know if you think that that also applies to economic policymaking, that maybe you do have some overlap with the people who traditionally would have been on the right, you're on the left, because the divide is a little different. Right versus left doesn't even necessarily make sense anymore.

I think there's something to that. Well, first, let me start by disagreeing a little bit, which is that there are a set of policies that are still kind of more associated with left versus right. And if I were arguing with an economist like Michael Strain, a good sort of right-leaning economist who's not, you know, a MAGA guy, we would argue about the minimum wage

And I don't mean just him, but minimum wage, unions, union bargaining clout, probably some safety net kinds of issues. So there's still left-right divides between economists. But yeah, I think your institutionalist point is well taken.

I think the deterioration of key institutions is, you know, I think that's a real threat to the economy. And I think there's a lot of conservative economists who would agree with me. Here's a good example, Fed independence. A lot of this stuff comes down to cases.

I would say, you know, most good economists believe that Fed independent federal central bank independence is really important. And you'll find left and right, you know, agreeing on that. You are also something of a throwback, if not in Washington, then maybe just in life, I guess, like you're very much.

a true gentleman, you know, even towards the people that you disagree with. I've never or rarely heard you get personal when you disagree with somebody about, you know, policy or economics. You have, I think, been unflaggingly loyal to President Biden, but I also imagine that you did not win every single policy argument inside the White House. You imagine correctly. And I might even be exaggerating that point a little bit. And it'd be great now to hear some of your more full, comprehensive views on

of various issues. But let me first just ask what the process of economic policymaking looked like, the decision making looked like while you were in the White House, especially most recently, when you had a big issue where there were various considerations. So there's the economic policy advice, which you provided. There were maybe political considerations. Maybe there were, I don't know,

distributional trade-offs. Like if we do this, yes, it's good for this group of folks, but not good for this group of folks. Like who's in the room with you when you're advising the president on that kind of thing? Are the politics people there? Do you give your advice and then they show up later? Is everybody in the room simultaneously? How did that work? Well, there are various stages. So a lot of times a policy process will start out with a group of, well, I think we would call them deputies. So folks who were

I guess you have to start with the hierarchy. So you have the president, then you have the senior staff, the cabinet, I would put it that level. So president, senior staff slash cabinet, and then deputies and folks who would help them do their work. So somebody would come up with an idea. It might be the president, it might be the senior staff, it might be one of the principals for an economic policy. And what

And we would ask the deputies to scrum around and give us a memo or a little white paper on what that would do. So we're thinking about, you know, do we need to add tariffs on certain things that we're trying to subsidize so we avoid unfair traders capturing market share that we don't want them to have?

So that would be, it would start with deputies doing the economic analysis and it would work its way up that ladder until you're sitting with the president in the Roosevelt room or the Oval Office and he's looking at a decision memo, sir, should we do this or not? And he kind of checks yes or no. Okay. And then-

When you feel things tilting either in your favor or against you, do you do anything else or do you feel like your job is done at that point? Like I've given the advice, the president has what he needs, you know, or if you hear somebody say, hey, well, I don't know, politically, this might not play well, even though you think it's the right thing to do.

in economic terms, do you say, well, but Mr. President, don't forget about this or whatever? Like, do you get back involved or are you like, nope, he's got what he needs now, I'm done? I typically wouldn't be in that meeting with the president and be fighting with my

other principals and saying, sir, you know, I disagree with them. You should go my way. This kind of thing is usually resolved before you get to the president. If you have a different view than your colleagues and your fellow, you know, principals, you kind of try to work that out. Sometimes you win, sometimes you lose. By the time you get to the president, at least in my experience, you're pretty well

align. Now, there have been times when Biden and I were together and we might talk a little bit more informally about something and I might try to nudge him one way or the other. And, you know, I've had a little success and a lot of non-success in those conversations. In the non-success situations,

How do you process that? Like, how do you sort of still go out? For example, sometimes you have to go on TV or the radio and defend the overall economic approach of the president. That's part of your job. Knowing that behind the scenes, you might not have gotten your way on something. Yeah, that was hard for me. And, you know, I'm thinking of concrete examples. And a lot of times the way I would talk about it would be, you know, the president has decided this and, you know, that's what we're going to do.

What's your favorite concrete example? I think the most recent one would be the decision to block Nippon Steel from purchasing U.S. Steel. That was one that I thought that deal kind of made sense. And one thing that was interesting to me about that was...

while the president was listening to the management of the U.S. steel workers and, to his credit, listening to them in ways that I think other presidents didn't. So I do give him a lot of, again, a lot of credit for taking the unions and the management seriously versus just sort of the banking sector. So I'm glad that he listened to them. There were rank and file folks who were saying, no, we want this deal to go through. So it was a tricky one. And, you know, I was on the other side of that. Yeah.

You know, I would go on TV and I'd say, here's the statement from the president. I'd sometimes even read the statement. And, you know, that was true. I made a point of never saying anything I couldn't defend or didn't think was true. So I wouldn't go up there and say, boy, I fought for this because I believed it was right. But, you know, neither would I say, hey, by the way, TV station, you know, I was against this one. You know, I would never say that. Try to finesse it a little bit. No, you want it.

It's really important to be a team player and to speak with one voice. And, you know, you wrote about this on your Substack now, which everybody should go subscribe to, by the way. Here's what you wrote. You wrote...

Blocking the Nippon Steel bid is a better example for those who accused us, the Biden administration, of being too protectionist. And I'm sympathetic to that critique. But you can also read that as the president listening to and taking seriously the concerns of the steelworkers union. And then you added in parentheses, though there was a dispute here between union management and rank and file.

This is why I think I give the president a lot less credit than you might here in terms of listening to the union, because here the pro-economy position was also very much the pro-worker position. Like this seemed like a slam dunk to me, you know, and Japan is an ally. We're in the middle of trying to figure out trade policy towards, you know, the universe of our allies versus our adversaries. That loomed large for me. You know, I thought...

Japan's an important ally. And so, yeah, I didn't like where we landed there. So obviously here, the China trade war was, if anything, accelerated under the Biden administration after President Trump essentially started it. There have been tensions there for a while, but President Trump really amped it up and then President Biden sort of doubled down on it. And that's still, I think, where we are, right?

Versus like our allies, do you think that there should be a lot more globalization with our allies than we have right now, if only to make sure that we bring everybody a little bit closer into our orbit? And do you think we've done enough of that?

I generally think we should have all the globalization we can with our allies. So I'm very pro that kind of policy with our trading partners. Like when I think about resilient supply chains, which is something we talk about a lot, became very important, of course, in these years. Some people say resilient supply chain. In fact, I would kind of argue China's there right now would say resilient supply chains meaning means produce as much as you can domestically.

I think resilient supply chains means definitely produce domestically in areas that are sensitive, but also buddy up with a lot of friendly trading partners so you can expand your supply chain. So I'm for that. I just want to be careful, Cardiff, about this because you have to... A lot of this comes down, especially when you've been in the government as much as I have, a lot of this comes down to nuance, to cases. So when I say we should...

have all the globalization with our partners, with our friendly trading partners that we can. I'm also mindful of the fact that there are communities that have been really foundationally hurt by persistent trade imbalances. And we can't ignore that either. And I think that's the root of my, and I think CEA under my leadership, are both and trade policy, which means

both recognizing the benefits and costs of globalization. Yeah, funny thing happens when the mics are on here, right? And...

It becomes very easy when we're talking about this stuff to get a little bit guarded, right? I get that way too. I'm like a little bit less myself when the mics are on, but it's a funny thing and our listeners obviously couldn't see it. When I brought up trade in an area where you disagreed with President Trump, your body language totally changed, right? Like you started hugging your chest. So this is meant to be an expansive chat. This is not a gotcha chat. Like I have some questions about all these things, but I think this is all really interesting.

And I think our listeners are going to benefit from it. And in the case of trade, I was talking to a friend of mine yesterday about this and about how presidents, essentially what they do when it comes to the ability to like start or accelerate trade wars or scale them back, they always kind of like pass the gun off to the next person, the next president, right?

At no point is there an effort, for example, to devolve power away from the executive and make it harder to move trade and put that in the hands of Congress, right? So in the case, and this goes back as far as you want,

It always stays there. And one of my sort of frustrations there is that you're always on edge. So you might get like relative stability, for example, under President Biden, but President Trump then gets elected and he's still got the gun. It's like, we just handed off the gun. We didn't, I don't know, to extend the metaphor, put the gun into a vault and give the keys to Congress, right? It seems to me like that might be a good idea at some point so that you don't get this just like,

extraordinary power to cite whatever justification you want to impose a huge trade war, which leads to a ton of uncertainty. And I think it's bad for the economy in the long term. There's a lot I like about that argument, but there's a fatal flaw in it, which is Congress. Yeah.

I mean, you really want to hand that over to this Congress? I have no faith in their ability to do a better job, particularly, I would say, the Republicans. So now I'm being partisan, who seem completely subservient to Trump and completely rejecting some of the basic benefits of globalization that I was just referring to. So the extent of Trumpian protectionism seems to have

very much infected that party. Does the president have too much power to set trade policy by him or herself? Yeah, I would agree with that. I think that's clear. And when I kind of grew up, Congress had much more power to determine the direction of trade policy than the executive branch, the Ways and Means Committee was supposed to decide

things like tariffs. And that's been completely handed over to the executive branch. And as we see, not only is it a problem in terms of bad policy, it's a problem, I think this was implicit in your statement, in terms of lurching, the extent to which policy lurches from president to president, which I think is really, really bad for the framework. I think on trade, which is one of the most interesting areas that I think about these days,

trade or globalization, international policies, I actually think we were working towards a pretty good balance in the Biden administration. I know that we did some things that were maybe too protectionist. And I know that people probably don't recognize the following, which is that we really valued trade flows and trade flows stayed very robust. They didn't really go down at all. For

Foreign direct investment, FDI, was especially robust coming into this country. And if you look at exports and imports as a share of the economy, they didn't really change or go down much at all. In fact, trade deficits as a share of our GDP was pretty stable over that period. So I think we believed in robust flows. We just maybe didn't talk about it that way very much.

If we remember back in the Trump administration, the first one, you know, that the trade war with China started, but we also started imposing a lot of tariffs on our allies and for some, frankly, like quite dubious reasons, you know. It looks like we're headed that way again, by the way. You've made the distinction between certain kinds of targeted tariffs for specific strategic reasons, whether it's national security, whether it's reasons of resiliency. Those things are all part of very, like, vigorous debates

It's not so much resiliency as like cheating. Basically, if somebody's dumping rubber tires grade four on your economy to grab market share there, you should tariff them. Yeah, by resilience, I meant something like having, you know, a homegrown domestic semiconductor manufacturing capability. Right. So that it's here and so that maybe then we're a little bit less reliant on other companies.

countries. And again, I want to say that none of these arguments is sort of a slam dunk in either direction. They're still being debated now. I personally am not sure where I am on some of these topics, right? But you draw the distinction between those kinds of tariffs and protectionist measures versus kind of willy-nilly across the board. Sweeping tariffs. Sweeping protectionism, that kind of thing. And

One thing that I also don't see presidents do a lot or Congress or anybody else these days, frankly, because it's not a very popular thing, is reinvigorating like the global liberal trading order, you know, rehabilitating, for example, the status of the World Trade Organization. And it seems to me like that was one of like the big victories of the post-World War period is,

And it seems to be greatly diminished now. So even if we point to some measures, like, for example, trade flows, that kind of thing, like the threat that this incredible achievement will still be undone remains.

I see what you're saying and I partially agree, but I think the WTO, as far as I can tell, has kind of devolved into a pretty sclerotic organization and not at all nimble on its feet the way I think you need to be in this world. So I also think that one thing that's missing from our conversation on trade so far is this little thing called politics.

And I recognized under the Trump one that thumbing your nose at the WTO was a feature, not a bug, was a sign of strength. And tariffs, even sweeping tariffs, looked again like flexing your muscles and beating up on those who would take advantage of you.

And so while I have come from a place of, listen, folks, we need to have robust supply chains that are closely linked with trading partners whom we can largely trust, as well as domestic production where we need to pick up the slack. That's all very pragmatic kind of econ 101. I think none of us have dealt sufficiently well.

with the political implications, the fact that if you stand up and say, I'm for tariffing the hell out of everybody, apparently there's a chunk of the electorate that really likes that. Yeah, it's interesting. Because if you think of trade on a spectrum, where on one side of the spectrum is full protectionism, or whatever you want to call it, mercantilism, autarky, isolationist, whatever. And then on the entire other side of the spectrum, you have open season, no trade barriers whatsoever.

I would say I'm probably a little bit further towards the open season side than you are, but I get the sense that you're closer to the open season side than –

President Biden, certainly way more over there than like President Trump, that kind of thing. Like how would you position yourself on that spectrum? Closer to the open season, but very much suspicious of the way trade deals and relationships play out without guardrails. I mean, it's like we were talking about with opportunity zones, without guardrails, this kind of thing can be taken advantage of. So one of the things that I did that I wonder if even a scholar as deep as yourself has done is I've read trade deals.

with a lawyer sitting next to me to help me understand them. And, you know, trade deals are not, a lot of times people portray trade deals as at the open season part of the continuum. That's just BS. I mean, if that were the case, they wouldn't be 1,200 pages. A lot of times they're, you know, handshakes between special interests.

And so I'm always suspicious of the power dynamics and how it's distorting something. But the reason I'm closer to the open season, especially having gone through what I went through in 21, 22 with supply chain snarl ups, is just how important it is to an economy to have a robust supply side. And you're right what you said a minute ago about globalization is a gift in that regard. Right.

And we should treat it as such, but we should be mindful of distortions and corruptions by power grabbers. Let's change topics now. Answer this question in whatever direction you want. What's the single thing that you're most proud of having accomplished during the Biden years? Maintaining full employment labor markets for almost the whole period. Unemployment went low and it stayed low the whole time. Yep. Okay. And then the other side, what is the thing you'd say is your biggest regret?

Well, how much time do you have? I think the messaging of which I was a part of, I regret some of what I... The messaging? Yeah, some of what I did there. And then I think there's a critique on inflation that we need to get into that I've been doing a lot of noodling over. Yeah. So on the messaging...

There were a lot of times where, you know, I can picture myself sitting there. We called it WHNL, White House North Lawn. That was when we would stand out there and talk to the TVs, where I can picture myself talking about a positive report. And we had a lot of positive reports, a good GDP report, a good CPI report, a good jobs report. We had killer jobs reports where we were just creating gangbuster jobs and kind of talking past people by emphasizing the strength of the overall economy.

Now, I give myself some forgiveness there because there was a view, and I think was correct, that if we didn't tell our good news story, nobody else would. The media was really kind of tilted against us in this regard. And I know if it bleeds, it leads. That's kind of a traditional thing. But the negativity on the economy was really excessive.

And so we had to tell our good news story. But there's a way in which I feel like I talked past a lot of people who were really struggling with high prices, which, by the way, we all always said the president always said that it was a paragraph in there.

But I do think people thought we were gaslighting them at best and clueless at worst when we were talking about the true and positive things about the overall economy. But what could you have done differently in the messaging?

Well, that's the right question. And A, I'm not sure what I've done differently. I have some ideas. But B, probably more importantly, I don't think it would have made any difference. I don't think if we had better messaging, there'd be some cosmic change or electoral change that would have occurred. I

I think it would have made sense to probably do the following. You get a great GDP. GDP came in at 3%, which is an actual number I remember from one of the recent quarters. And that's above trend. That's a really strong indicator. It's really important, as you well know, for the overall economy to be growing at a rate like that.

And I would go in front of the cameras and I'd say, good news, folks. This morning, GDP came in at 3%. Now, I know a lot of you are still struggling with high prices, but we're doing all we can to help. I think it would have maybe been useful to flip that and say, yeah, we got a good report this morning. But hey, I know that everybody out there is really struggling with the price level right now and that folks have a lot of concerns about this. And we do too. And we're working at it.

A good thing happened this morning. GDP came in strong. Now, you can't eat GDP and you can't, you know, it doesn't change the price of eggs at the grocery. I get that. But this is a movement in the right direction. And maybe try to explain to folks how that kind of economic dynamic is important and how it can help in the longer run. So maybe it was sort of flipping the script a little bit.

So if you look back at what happened in those post-COVID years, you know, GDP got back to trend, back to its trend line of growth right from before the pandemic. That's a big deal. I think the separation with other countries was really impressive. You know, unemployment dropped.

Getting low, staying low, that I think is an achievement you can point to with a lot of pride. But people also struggle with counterfactuals, right? They struggle with comparisons too. I mean, most of us do, right? In our day-to-day lives, you know, we don't think in terms of, oh, things could have been so much worse, right?

It's hard to like appreciate that or to give people credit for that. Right. And simultaneously, there were some real problems. Like people hate inflation. They really hate inflation. And one of the things that I noticed last year, I mean, I didn't notice it. It was reported. It was released by the Fed, was that real median household incomes dropped.

were still slightly below in 2023 what they were in 2019. So this isn't just about, okay, we got back to trend growth. That's amazing. It's not just unemployment was low. A lot of people still really did not feel a sense of improvement.

And that, I think, is part of the con side. If you do a pro and con of what happened during the Biden years, that definitively real wages, real income, I think, has to go on the con side. And that was partly a product of the very high inflation eating into higher wages, but

But it's also something that then people experience directly, right? That sense of stagnation across three or four years. Yeah, I totally agree with that. And again, I think that some of the things that I was saying at the time in messaging context is,

Weren't respectful enough of that truth that you just shared. You're right about that. Now, it gets a little tricky because we actually had quite strong real wage growth starting later in the game than

was enough to make up for the gaps that you just mentioned. So if you look at real wage gains, and there's lots of different series, but starting in, you know, 22, 23 through 24, when inflation was coming down and the job market was staying strong, remember that it didn't take me long to tell you what I was most proud of. It's that full employment labor market. And the reason we like that is because, and I say we, because I had many partners at CEA who came from a similar place,

is because it does give workers more bargaining power. Biden talked about this in February of 2021 in his first economic speech. He talked about getting back to full employment. He said the words five times because it was important to him from this bargaining power perspective. And that started to kick in as inflation eased and we started to see strong real wage growth. But it was too late in the game to make up for the gaps that you were talking about. Still, this is kind of what I was saying a minute ago, that

We're moving in the right direction. We're on the right path. We're not where you need us to be yet, but we're making progress. There was an article that you're in the process of responding to right now by Jason Furman, who was one of your predecessors, actually, as chair of...

Also, again, to bring out the gentlemanly side of you, you said, all that said, in your response to Jason, Jason's a great economist and he gets some important things right, mistakes that we should learn from. These were your comments after Jason's article in Foreign Affairs was released.

You and I are talking on Tuesday, February 11th. You have not yet released your response to Jason, but I know it's coming. So let me just stop and ask though, when you say mistakes that we should learn from, what were those mistakes as you see them?

Well, I've already talked about one of them in terms of messaging. And then I think one of the points that Jason really leans into and others have as well is that the rescue plan contributed to inflation. The American rescue plan made a tough inflation situation worse. This was Biden's policy from 2021. And

And I think it was about a $2 trillion spending package, something like that. Right. The critique is that that was too large, unnecessarily so, given that the economy was already recovering and that by passing such a large package, we contributed to economic overheating. And, you know, I think there is some validity to that critique.

I also think that 2020 hindsight is a luxury we didn't have then. I was just looking at some numbers as I was working up a response. And, you know, the last jobs report we saw when we came in was a negative with employment down 140,000 and the unemployment rate stuck at 6.7%.

COVID deaths were peaking back then. The vaccine wasn't out. We were worried about business failures and evictions. So there was a real motivation to punch back hard against the impact of the COVID-induced recession.

But with hindsight, I think there's a credible argument that the rescue plan contributed to the inflation problem. However, and this gets to your counterfactual point, what I feel very firm about, and I think Jason gets quite wrong, is the idea that inflation would have been pretty close to what it was even without the rescue plan.

He very much seems to deny that there was a supply shock in the economy. I think that's unequivocally true. And I think that you can see that by looking at inflation evolution around the world, where inflation went up close to as much as it did here, sometimes even more, and they didn't do the same fiscal policy. So maybe inflation would have peaked at 7.5% instead of 9%, and I think we would have had a lot of the same problem.

But I think the argument that ARP contributed to the inflation problem is one that we should take seriously and learn from. I've seen a lot of the estimates from economists about how much of the inflationary episode was the result of

of the rescue plan being too big. Those estimates are kind of all over the place. Some people, I think like you say, it was maybe negligible. Others say it was as much as three percentage points. So if inflation went from two to 9% or whatever, it would have only gone to like six or 7%, if not for the size of the rescue plan.

I don't know which of those estimates is right. The argument that it would have been the same is that the one that you brought up, I think, which is that a lot of European countries who also were dealing with supply chain issues also had cumulative inflation that was about the same. On the other hand, I also see the argument that Europe was dealing with a way worse energy shock. So if cumulative inflation was the same, there's still a gap there to be explained in the US. You see what I mean? Yeah.

Yeah, I think that's right. And I'm trying to be upfront about that in both our conversation and my response to Jason. You're right. The quantitative estimates go from zero to 100%, really. And so the ones that I think are most...

Bernanke and Blanchard did some nice modeling of this. We at CEA also did similar work, and we came up with something in the range of one and two percentage points, so maybe one and a half. So again, I mean, I think if we'd had inflation that was –

7.5% peak instead of 9% peak, that would have been better. Would it have changed, say, electoral outcomes or would people have felt, you know, much better about their economic outlook? I'm not sure. That's that counterfactual you mentioned earlier. But it, you know, that's something we should learn from.

Yeah, that's interesting. And there was one other critique that Jason included in his piece that I wanted to ask you about, because this was something I was paying a lot of attention to in real time as it was happening. And I just want to get your thoughts. Here's what here's what Jason writes. He writes, quote, adding to the trouble, the Biden administration's laser like focus on the demand side came at the expense of addressing impediments to supply, such as

excessive obstacles to permitting processes related to building infrastructure. And then he goes on to support that argument afterwards. This was something that I have to be honest, like frustrated me too. It seemed like there were a lot of like really good ideas embedded in some of those big policy packages that ended up being passed under Biden. You know, the infrastructure bill, the inflation reduction bill, right? But it seemed like there was also, maybe for just for political reasons, some catering to like

I don't know if it was unions or environmentalists or whatnot, and not enough movement on undoing some of the bureaucratic obstacles to making things, to getting things done, to building things. Is that a critique that you disagree with? No, I don't necessarily disagree with that critique, but I do very much disagree with the statement you read from Jason. And I think there's more wrong than right with his article if we go through a lot of the different points, and this is one of them.

So we were very focused on the supply side. It was clear to us, in fact, I think clear to us, and it seems to be to him from reading his piece,

that supply chain snarl-ups were extremely impactful. Now, look, we knew some stuff that others didn't know. So one of the things that didn't really come out until later was there was a point where a couple, I think, I can't remember if it was one or two, semiconductor producers in Malaysia shut down. And lo and behold, because of COVID, and lo and behold, basically North American auto production shut down for at least two weeks.

I mean, that is a clear supply chain shock. And we put together something called the Supply Chain Disruption Task Force. I was a member. And we worked really hard to unsnarl those chains. We were quite successful working hand in glove with the private sector, the unions, the management side of the ports in helping to unsnarl. So let it be known that we worked hard on this. And to dismiss that or to not acknowledge that is a real oversight. But yes.

We could have and should have done more on the permitting side. It was politically blocked in ways that were above my pay grade, but I agree with your critique.

We're going to have to have Jason on at some point to respond to your response to him. And then we'll just keep you guys coming back in for, maybe I should have had him in here today. No, no, I'm going to do, here's what I'm going to do. If I can figure out how to do it. I think on Substack, you can like do a video, right? You can, yeah. So I was thinking, I'm going to see, Jason is my good buddy. I mean, we are, we are like this. I'm doing the good buddy sign with my fingers. So I'm going to get him to do a video with me.

And we can go back and forth and I'll try not to- That's a good idea. Tell everybody. Yeah, that'll be fun to watch. I have a question about unions. You're kind of a longstanding supporter of unions, labor, and so forth, right? Founding member of the Economic Policy Institute Union, by the way. There you go.

And union membership as a share of the workforce has been declining for many decades now. We're down to about 6% of private sector workers. I think it's 10% of workers overall because there's a much higher share of public sector workers that are in unions. And something that I got to say has always frustrated me about the way that everybody talks about unions is that we seem not to apply the same kind of nuanced analysis that we do to say like, I don't know,

companies, businesses, nonprofits, whatever, it seems like the debate very often breaks down along like, are you pro-union, are you anti-union? As opposed to, for example, saying, well,

Well, there are some specific circumstances in which we definitely know that unions can do a lot of good. Let's say in an industry or in a place where there's a lot of monopsonistic power, right? Then you can point to what unions do and say, well, this gives workers a way to get, you know, what they deserve because the excess power of their employers are sort of keeping their wages down almost artificially, right? Mm-hmm.

But then there might be other circumstances where there are real trade-offs to union activity, or at least we can apply scrutiny to specific unions. Unions are run by human beings, right? These are the same kind of people like anybody else that can be, I don't know, seduced by the trappings of a very powerful, prestigious, perhaps in some cases even highly remunerative job, right? Mm-hmm.

And we don't seem to apply that kind of scrutiny to unions. Very often it is unions good, unions bad. That is my frustration, but I'm kind of curious to know as somebody who's much more, I think, an instinctive supporter of unions than I am. I'm curious to know what you think.

I think a couple of things. First of all, in both this topic and other topics you've raised, Cardiff, I think that you're often asking, and I'm very much sympathetic to this, for governments to operate in a far more nuanced way than they're good at.

That is the dream, isn't it? Yeah. I mean, if we could, you know, if you could run the show, then perhaps we could find the right positioning. Oh boy, would we be in trouble? The optimal positioning on those continua that you keep citing out. And I, you know, I don't disagree with you, but one of the reasons why I think everybody should work for the government, including you at some point, is that you learn that kind of being pro or against is just really the default position sometimes. And so, um,

while your nuances are well taken, they're hard to operationalize because you've got strong forces that are pro, there are strong forces that are against. And meanwhile, you're dealing with a war in Ukraine. So there's a lot going on. That's fair. But I'm partly, by the way, applying this almost as a self-critique, right? I was a journalist for many years before I joined EIG. And it seems to me like that is the way that not just policymakers and people in government, politicians talk about unions, but the way

almost everybody talks about unions. By the way, I'm as bothered by like reflexively anti-union sentiment as I am by reflexively pro-union sentiment. I just want people to like better understand, you know, where there are trade-offs, what those trade-offs are. Like is a given union doing a good job or a bad job? It's a really important question. And let me help you, I think, in a workaround, which is the way I operate in this space. What you want to be concerned about is less what's the percentage of union density and

and more about what kind of bargaining power do workers have to get a fair shake. That's what you want to worry about. The reason you want union power to be in the mix, and I think I can speak for the president in this, is because he recognizes that if workers are going to get a fair slice of the pie that they're helping to bake, they need more bargaining clout.

Your monopsony example is a good one. I don't know how many pure monopsodies are out there, but I think it's a pervasive problem. I think that the average worker sitting across the table, metaphorically, from the average employer just doesn't have enough clout to get their fair shake. And so that's why we like to see full employment. We like to see union power. We like to see rules like minimum wages to ensure that people have more bargaining clout.

And when unions act in ways that don't promote bargaining clout, when they act in ways that are overly protectionist or something, you know, we should oppose that. But they are one of the most enduring and last standing institutions in

created to fight on behalf of worker bargaining clout. And that's one reason why I'm a longtime supporter. What about, for example, what happened with the Port Workers Union? I mean, those guys straight up said, we don't want any automation. This is nuts, right? This is something where we are supposed to favor an economy that does evolve over time and that is good for workers over time with rising fast productivity growth. Like these guys were- Correct. Come on. But-

Well, no, you come on. Okay, fine. And I'll tell you why. Go ahead. Because look at what happened in their contract. They accepted some degree of automation, maybe not as much as you like, or frankly, not as much as I'd like. But to criticize their out-of-the-gate bargaining position is to kind of miss the dynamics of what they were up to. I mean, it may sound nuts to you, but to them and their membership in that kind of an argument, it made sense to them. So-

Again, I agree that there can be an anti-technology or a protectionist dimension to this that kind of gets into this collision between bargaining clout and good economics. And that's a hard place to resolve. But I do appreciate the bargaining power point. Here's something you and I have talked about in the past. This is a conversation that goes back years, which is the idea that when you have full employment—

It not only is good for workers because they have more bargaining power, they can get wage growth, but also it incentivizes companies to start investing in equipment, buildings, the kinds of things that lead to faster productivity growth over time, that that can be a real incentive.

It's also something that's been very hard for economists to study. I think it's a tricky kind of methodological challenge to figure out if that relationship really does apply. It's something that to me seems to make a lot of sense, you know?

During the Biden years, we had full employment for a few years. And I think, you know, as far as I can tell, investment did not quite get back to that pre-pandemic trend. But productivity growth has been impressive the last few years, which itself might be kind of an interesting disconnect there. So I'm kind of curious to know what your views are on this idea now.

It's very similar to what you said. I mean, I do think, and I hope, that there is a linkage between full employment and productivity improvements through the kind of chain that you just articulated. If firms want to maintain their profitability in a full employment climate where there's upward wage pressure, they have to discover new efficiencies that they were leaving on the table otherwise.

Now, you and I came up in an economics that said if you're leaving efficiencies on the table, you're kind of going to instantaneously go out of business. But that's wrong. There are a lot of companies that operate with all kinds of slack, and full employment sort of forces them, again, if they want to maintain profit margins, to find ways to produce more efficiently. And there's some correlation, but it's very hard to measure for technical reasons.

That said, and I always try to be mindful of confirmation bias, things I want to be true, I do think there is some evidence on behalf of that connection. By the way, on the investment front, I actually think we did pretty well. And I thought that real business investment, at least, did get back on trend. And of course, if you look at some of the areas where we incentivized more investment, the construction of a lot of new factories, for example, we did very well in that regard.

What do you think about manufacturing in the US? Because one of the things that actually some colleagues of mine at EIG were looking at was that

If you look at manufacturing employment, right? So let's not talk yet about manufacturing output, right? Manufacturing employment, this was the first recovery from a recession where the absolute level of manufacturing employment actually did get back to where it was before the recession started. So that part of it so far, so good, right? I think for the last couple of years, it's been pretty flat. And as a share of the economy, it does continue to fall. You mean as a share of the employment?

- As a share of the labor force, right? Manufacturing employment continues to fall. Simultaneously, the place where manufacturing employment has recovered is not actually the places where it had been collapsing for all those decades. It wasn't in the Rust Belt. It was actually in the parts of the economy throughout the country

where the economy was doing well anyways. You see what I mean? Like places like in the Sunbelt, right? Where the economy was doing great and manufacturing jobs are coming back there, but not in those communities where it had fallen in the first place, right? And then there is the huge boom that I think is still ongoing

in factory construction. And we don't yet know what the eventual outcome, we might not know for 10 years or something, what the eventual outcome of all that building will be. Will it work? Could. So there's a kind of an interesting picture emerging of manufacturing inside the US. What is your sort of take on where it is and where it's going?

Well, first of all, one piece that I think you left out of the analysis you just shared is that the latter thing you said about those factories being constructed, those do seem to be occurring disproportionately in geographical areas that have been historically left behind. Yes, but the employment recovery in those places has not gone all the way back to where it was before. And, you know, you got to build the church before the people come in. So, yeah. Yeah.

So I'm sorry, what's, you packed a lot of- I did, I did. I just wanted to get your sense of manufacturing in the US. Is it even a big deal? Should we be spending a ton of time making services jobs better? Is that as Paul Krugman has argued recently? What do you think? So definitely, yes. Paul's right about that. I wrote a piece about it. And I'll say a little bit more about that in a second. People accused us of having a manufacturing job fetish.

And, you know, I'm somewhat sympathetic to that critique, but I do think that sector is disproportionately important, both in terms of supply chain resiliency. And if you go back to the earlier part of our conversation, I was very clear that such resiliency doesn't just mean the domestic route. It does mean obviously being open to global trade with trusted partners. But I do think that more domestic production, both in terms of economic and national security for things like

chips and some of the clean energy production is important. But I worry that you can overemphasize, and perhaps we fell into this, the importance of manufacturing employment over service employment. Because as we said, if manufacturing is 8%, then everything else is 92%. And that's where so much of the job growth is occurring. I mean, healthcare, education, those kinds of services, really important. And

And, you know, again, I wrote about this recently and was very, I think, you know, tried to be very forthright about this point. And Paul was spot on. There's a lot more we need to do to improve the quality of service jobs. You know, I think union can be helpful there and full employment as well. But basically just as a society valuing child care workers and teachers and health care workers way more than we do strikes me as a really important and forward looking goal.

Where are you on immigration as economic policy? Well, I think it's really important to have a secure border. I don't think if countries are defined by borders and if your border is thoroughly porous, then it's hard to argue that you have a country. So we make a distinction between legal and illegal or undocumented immigration. I think that's a relevant one.

But all that said, and I've always thought we should be welcoming in that regard, and immigrants are a tremendously important part of this country, both economically, culturally, and in every other way I can think of.

Here, I'm going to throw you one that I think you like. I was talking to Andrew Seeley of the Migration Policy Institute for this podcast last year. One of the points he made that I think is underappreciated was the extent to which Biden helped fix the legal immigration process. And in particular, there were some technologies that we started using during COVID that

that ended up being resilient, that we ended up continuing to use. And so legal immigration ended up rebounding quite strongly during the Biden years. I don't know what's going to happen now, but this is something that I look at a lot. And in terms of undocumented immigration,

What's fascinating to me is the extent to which a lot of what happened at the border during the Biden years might have also been driven by the fact that the U.S. economy was outpacing almost every other advanced world economy, right? Every other advanced economy. And so it just was a much more attractive place for immigrants to get to. In other words, it was in large part an economic story and not just a story of, I don't know,

collapsing security or whatever. That was not a message that I heard a lot from either the Biden folks, because I think it would have been a politically toxic argument, and certainly not from the Trump folks either. But it was an argument that seems to have a lot of truth to it. And I thought I should just mention it here and also give you some props for helping fix legal immigration.

Well, thank you. And, you know, the credit goes to folks on our staff who worked really hard on, I don't mean CEA, I mean within the White House, who worked really hard on that with exactly those goals in mind. So thank you for recognizing that. You know, this is one of those issues where when you go on TV, you're sort of crossing your fingers and hope that they don't ask you about it because it... Because you get aggregated, man. The bloggers and the people on Twitter come after you. It's so hard to talk about. I have a congenital...

favorable view towards immigration. And again, as I said a moment ago, the contribution that they've made to America is huge and ongoing. I think that, you know, you make a good and I think well-established empirical point about the economic pull factor.

What I think we also have to recognize is that the message that sort of presidents and administrations send about how open or welcome your border is also seems to have a really significant impact on flows. And, you know, that's something I think we should also be mindful of. Where are you on housing? I think that one of the biggest pieces of unfinished business is

in our administration was our inability to get Congress to deal with the depth of what I would call a crisis, a housing affordability, a housing supply crisis. It's something I worked on every week in our time there. I think we did as much as we could without Congress, but that and I would say childcare are two areas where the affordable supply was something we needed to do more work on.

On housing in particular, what should be the approach of the federal government to housing? Because so often I see this very kind of, I don't want to say defeatist, but certainly very pessimistic attitude about what the federal government can do, just to talk around the book for a little bit. But like at EIG, we're trying to figure out ways that the federal government can incentivize good behavior for housing.

from local and state governments, right, to get more housing built, to rezone, to do things better. What do you think? Totally agree. We tried to implement some policies. We had some success in that direction. But like, what does the government do? I mean, one of the things we do is we write checks to localities. So putting conditions on them in terms of pushing back on exclusionary zoning makes a ton of sense.

I don't know that we can make anywhere near the progress we need to make unless we can see less exclusionary zoning. That has to be opened up. But look, I think the federal government can do, you know, a lot, maybe more than you just suggested, to help solve the pencil-out problem. One of the biggest problems we have—and it's related to zoning, but it's not the only force—

is that if you're a developer and you have resources to build, it's almost completely outside of your interest to build affordable housing. The only thing that makes financial sense for you to is build upper end housing. And that's what we mean when we say these projects don't pencil out.

Our housing team came up with lots of good ideas that we think would have added millions of affordable units by helping to subsidize the building of affordable housing. By the way, I think the GSEs, Fannie and Freddie, can play more of a role. They've actually been pushing in the right direction. I think they can play more of a role there. And it's something that a colleague who worked on housing, Daniel Hornung, and I are writing a piece on that right now.

I think in either the most recent or one of the recent economic reports of the president that CEA puts together, there was a lot in there about AI and its potential effects on the economy. What

What do you think is going on right now in terms of its current effects, say, on productivity versus what the future might hold? I mean, that's an impossible question to ask almost anybody, but I'm wondering if you have any kind of leanings so far. I've had some leanings. I mean, I think our chapter was very strong. So the following critique I'm about to make doesn't apply to our chapter, which really framed out the kinds of things you'd want to look at if you wanted to answer that question. AI is the thing that we say most about and know least about.

So I don't want to spend a lot of time on this. But I, again, I'm concerned about confirmation bias that is saying what I want to happen is happening. I guess I like to think that it may end up being more of a compliment than a substitute. I think there's some evidence for that in terms of labor. You know, the idea of these technologies is that are they going to replace people as substitutes? Are they going to compliment workers by making them more productive? We've

seen a little bit of evidence for the latter, but we have to be worried about the former too. You mentioned at the very start of our conversation that you're very worried about some of the things that are happening now from the new administration, from President Trump. You mentioned, what was it? Rule of law versus the law of rule? Is that how you phrase it? Yeah. I'm stealing that from somebody I saw say that. Yeah. What are you most worried about?

And in terms of the economy in particular, since that's what we're here to discuss, I'm sort of wondering what are the big concerns you have? Well, right now, I would say my biggest concern—maybe it's not quite the economy, though the economy is in there—

is that there's no institutional blockages to illegal activities. So that, to make it more concrete, we now see courts starting to block them. What happens if they ignore that? That, to me, strikes kind of constitutional crisis territory. So that would be my biggest worry. You know, on the economy, I...

I've made the same points that everybody's made about sweeping tariffs. They do exacerbate inflation. And that's the last thing we'd want to do right now. I think one of the problems facing the incoming administration is I worry that some of those folks, maybe not the economics team, but some of those folks think that 2025 equals 2017 in terms of some underlying dynamics. Like back then, you were missing inflation from the downside. Now we're still trying to get back to the inflationary target.

Back then, interest rates were very low and very steady. Now we've seen upward pressure on interest rates. So almost everything they're doing strikes me as potentially inflationary and increasing of the term premium, which is the part of the interest rate that goes up, but making investors want a higher return to lock up their lending, to lock up

their credit. So I worry that they're going to exacerbate inflation. And I think an even deeper concern is the potential, I think it's probably small, but it's not zero, to de-anchor inflationary expectations. You know, this is the idea that if you screw around with price setter psychology enough,

They won't believe that the Fed has a credible plan or ability to get inflation back to target. And those anchored expectations, they've actually been a national treasure in terms of our economic policy. Screwing around with that is really playing with fire. In terms of debt and deficits, I think we're now running...

The biggest, let me see if I remember this correctly, I think peacetime non-recessionary deficits ever, you know, and if you look at the trajectory of future deficits and the trajectory of the debt in the future, so much of it comes from things like Social Security, Medicare, things that we essentially established to help people in old age because the country is aging. And

I don't know, stabilizing that trajectory somehow without addressing those things seems awfully tough, but that is politically obviously like super toxic and difficult to get into. So I'm kind of curious to know, like, what do you think about the debt and deficits? What are some realistic but really good solutions there? Yeah.

I'm worried about them more so than I have been in the past. I don't think we're in trouble in the near term. I mean, if you want, one thing to do in this space is to look at the auctions for U.S. debt, and they tend to continue to go very well. We have, it's a very desired asset. We have large

global markets with strong demand for that asset to this day. So I'm not predicting a problem anytime in the near future, but the way you teed it up is exactly right. We are on an unsustainable trend and everybody knows that and nobody wants to do anything about it. In terms of the solution, I think we're thinking about it kind of the wrong way. I myself have, I think, you know, I'm doing a rethink myself. I've always said,

Scott Bessant, I heard the Treasury Secretary on TV saying, you know, we don't have a revenue problem. We have a spending problem. And I counter, we don't have a spending problem. We have a revenue problem. And I think I'm more right than he is. But I think that both of those framings are not really helpful. I think the problem that we have...

is one that economists call revealed preferences, which is don't believe what I say, look at what I do. And I think that both the country and the politicians who represent them want X amount of goods and services and want to pay, you know, one half X for it.

And that is, of course, unsustainable. And the thing that nobody seems to want to just admit is that we want X, damn it. We want Social Security. We want Medicaid. We want all that stuff. And we don't want you to cut it. And politicians keep telling us,

Oh, well, you don't have to cut it and then we can go on our merry way and spend and cut taxes. You know, that's not true. What we have to come to terms with is the things we want and just be comfortable with admitting that we really like social insurance and we really like, and if you like it, then you have to pay for it. And so it's not so much a spending problem as to stop bullshitting yourself on revealed preference problem. Okay. And yeah,

If you do that, though, you still run into, like, the problem of trade-offs, right? Like, the idea of if you want these things, you have to pay for it. Presumably, you mean you got to raise taxes, right? Absolutely. Okay. Contrary to my friend Jason, we think about trade-offs all the time. And we did in the administration. And in fact, we did— To be clear, Jason does think about trade-offs. He accuses—

the Bidenistas of not thinking about trade-offs. He does think about trade-offs. Well, so do we. I'm not saying you don't. I'm saying I just want to be accurate about what you said. That accusation is fully inaccurate. And so, you know, look at our budgets. Now, did they go far enough?

Probably not in the spirit of our conversation, but they were directionally correct. We tried to raise trillions of dollars through tax increases and we cut hundreds of billions of spending, particularly in the area of what I would call pretty inefficient healthcare. You know, getting Medicare the ability to bargain for prescription drugs is a small example. That's a couple hundred billion. A small example of what I'm talking about. But, you know, we wrote budgets that started to move in the right direction, but of course they had no political traction.

So, you know, we're very much aware of those trade-offs and recognize, you know, I said in the beginning of this conversation, we have more of a revenue problem than a spending problem. So, yes, if you look at where our revenues are relative to where they should be, there are a couple of points of GDP below that.

And that's what you get when you just keep cutting taxes on a one-way ratchet. But I do think the more fundamental problem is just admitting to ourselves through revealed preferences what it is that we want. You know, arithmetic being what it is.

you have to pay for what you want yeah i want to close with a few personal questions uh if i may actually no it's it's a good this is um and i want to keep that same animated spirit that you just that you just showed there what do you think is a big thing that in your decades of public service you have uh you've changed your mind about okay i got i've got one yeah so when i came up being a good progressive economist

And through the Economic Policy Institute was where I really learned so much about how the economy really works. I thought about market failures all the time. I saw ways in which markets fail people, people of color, communities in which power imbalances leave large swaths of folks behind, fueling the inequality, all things that I think are very familiar to you. I didn't appreciate enough government failures.

So that's sort of my assumption was, well, market's failing here, government can fix it there. I've learned a lot more, part of this has to do with working for the government all these years, is ways in which governments also can fail. So, you know, that's something that I think has informed my thinking. What are you most hopeful about?

Maybe even if it's personal, not necessarily for the economy at large, like are you excited about your next chapter, whatever it's going to be? I know you've got something more cooking than just sub stacking, but it seems like you're at least having a lot of fun doing that. Well, yeah, I mean, I think I'm hopeful about, you know, my personal future in the sense that I have a lot more time now to exercise and try to get my health back on track, things like that.

Look, I mean, I engage with a lot of people, you said it earlier, from both sides of the aisle. And I get the sense when I talk to people, especially people with different sensibilities, different political outlook, I get the sense that there's more of an urgency to have good conversations about this stuff than there used to be. Maybe it's too late. Maybe the Visigoths are in the building in ways that, you know, will bring us all down. That looks like a distinct possibility.

But the extent to which people of different persuasions are starting to talk to each other represents a kind of urgency that if we don't figure this out, we're all screwed. And I like that. That gives me a little bit of hope.

You started out as a musician. Your undergraduate was in music. It wasn't in economics. And I'm kind of curious to know what your experience is as a musician in the 1980s. I think you were a jazz musician, if I'm not mistaken. How did that sort of like inform what you went on to do with your life? Was it a matter of just doing something you loved? Yeah.

in some sense, getting it out of your system? Or was it something that you sort of still carry with you and carried with you throughout all these years of... Well, there's a lot of dimensions to that question. Let me start from right now, because there's another area where I'm a little hopeful, which is I bought a new electric base and I really love it.

I play the upright bass, but I'm getting a little long in the tooth to handle that. So I got this very cool electric bass. I'll show you a picture of it later. All right. And I'm having a ton of fun with that. I play in a dad rock band called Blue North. We have a lot of fun. I think the answer to your question, sort of going back to my own personal history, look, if I was a much better musician, we probably wouldn't be sitting here talking right now. So, you know, there's partly that, but also...

New York City in the 1980s, yes, I was a jazz musician then, but it was also the case that there was terrible inequality, homelessness. I saw so many economic problems and so much suffering back then.

I would argue that the conversations I was having with my musician colleagues were not particularly instructive in terms of figuring out what to do about that. And I was raised with the view that if you're not part of the solution, you're part of the problem. And that motivated me, along with my lack of talent, to move into other directions. Too self-deprecating, man. Well, you've never heard me play. That's true. Fair enough.

But it's interesting then that you arrived at what you wanted to do with your life through observation, in some sense through experience, rather than learning about something almost more theoretically as an undergrad or in your studies. Well, you know, I did get a PhD in social welfare from Columbia University where I had to basically major in a discipline. And of course, it was economics. So, you know, I'm a card-carrying guy in that regard.

I mean, another thing about music, Cardiff, is that to this day, and I mean every day, it is my salvation. And, you know, I'm talking about everything from Bach and Mozart, you know, to Jimi Hendrix and Ray Charles and Kendrick Lamar. So I feel, you know, I feel really blessed by the ability to dig into that daily. Jared Bernstein, one of my favorite people to talk to. Thanks so much for doing this. My pleasure.

And that's our show for today. You can find links to everything we reference in today's episode, including Jared's new sub stack and the show notes for this episode.

The New Bazaar is a production of the Economic Innovation Group. Adrian Lilly is our sound engineer and our music is by Scott Lane and DJ Harrison of Subflora Studio. Please follow or subscribe to The New Bazaar on your app of choice. And if you enjoyed today's show, please leave us a review or tell a friend. If you want to get in touch, I'm on Twitter as at Cardiff Garcia, or you can email us at thenewbazaar at EIG.org. And we'll see you next episode.